scholarly journals The Transport Factor of Formation of the Era of Modern Economic Growth

2019 ◽  
Vol 14 (1) ◽  
pp. 154-179 ◽  

The article deals with the transport factor influence on the implementation of the Industrial Revolution and the transition from the “Malthusian” economy to modern economic growth. Attention is focused on the periods of economic history of the early Roman Empire and medieval China. It is noted that the level of socioeconomic development of the Roman Empire at the beginning of our era was close to that of Western Europe shortly before the Industrial Revolution. The conclusion is drawn that the Roman Empire fell into a “transport-institutional trap” which blocked the movement along the path of industrialization and economic growth. In medieval China, the level of socio-economic development corresponding to the threshold of the Industrial Revolution was also reached. At the same time, many transport restrictions were removed. In particular, deep-sea trade became possible, allowing the establishment of global economic ties. Nevertheless, its development was blocked by the state policy of isolationism, which led to the decline of the Chinese economy. In Western Europe, the accumulation of innovations in shipbuilding and navigation in transnational competition led to the beginning of ocean navigation in the 15th century, new lands pioneering and the development of intercontinental goods exchange. The resulting geographically diversified economy stimulated technological progress and supply of goods, and gave a powerful impact to the development of the institutions of capitalism. To ensure dynamic economic growth in the 21st century, it is necessary to remove the newly emerging transport restrictions through economic policies that stimulate entrepreneurial activity in the transport sector.

2021 ◽  
Author(s):  
Liam Brunt ◽  
Cecilia García-Peñalosa

Abstract A large literature characterizes urbanisation as resulting from productivity growth attracting rural workers to cities. Incorporating economic geography elements into a growth model, we suggest that causation runs the other way: when rural workers move to cities, the resulting urbanisation produces technological change and productivity growth. Urban density leads to knowledge exchange and innovation, thus creating a positive feedback loop between city size and productivity that initiates sustained economic growth. This model is consistent with the fact that urbanisation rates in Western Europe, most notably England, reached unprecedented levels by the mid-18th century, the eve of the Industrial Revolution.


2018 ◽  
pp. 22-54
Author(s):  
Şevket Pamuk

This chapter examines the trends in economic growth and human development in Turkey during the last two centuries. Economists have learned a great deal about modern economic growth since the end of World War II. The large and growing literature has emphasized that increases in productivity, achieved through technological progress on the one hand, and increases in per capita physical capital and education levels, on the other, were the most important factors contributing to economic growth. In addition, the labor force is much better educated than in 1820. In short, technological change and higher rates of investment in both physical and human capital are seen today as the leading proximate causes of economic growth since the Industrial Revolution.


2019 ◽  
Vol 129 (623) ◽  
pp. 2867-2887 ◽  
Author(s):  
Jane Humphries ◽  
Jacob Weisdorf

Abstract Estimates of historical workers’ annual incomes suffer from the fundamental problem that they are inferred from day wage rates without knowing how many days of work day-labourers undertook per year. We circumvent the problem by building an income series based on the payments made to workers employed by the year rather than by the day. Our data suggest that earlier annual income estimates based on day wages overestimate medieval labour incomes but underestimate labour incomes during the Industrial Revolution. Our revised estimates indicate that modern economic growth began more than two centuries earlier than commonly thought and was driven by an ‘Industrious Revolution’. They also suggest that the current global downturn in labour's share is not exceptional but fits within the range of historical fluctuations.


1964 ◽  
Vol 23 (3) ◽  
pp. 377-381 ◽  
Author(s):  
Sydney Crawcour

The fact that England, the home of the Industrial Revolution and modern economic growth, was also a leading shipping and trading nation, at one time prompted the notion that flourishing overseas trade and modern economic growth are somehow related. There are, of course, plenty of examples in European history of once flourishing trading nations which failed to industrialize. Spain, Portugal, the Hanseatic ports, and the Italian trading cities never became centres of industry. Moreover, such comparatively industrialized areas as Czechoslovakia and Prussia were not leading trading centres.


Sign in / Sign up

Export Citation Format

Share Document