Equilibrium investment-reinsurance strategy with delay and common shock dependence under Heston's SV model

Optimization ◽  
2021 ◽  
pp. 1-32
Author(s):  
Sheng Li ◽  
Zhijian Qiu
Keyword(s):  
Author(s):  
Marco Lippi

High-dimensional dynamic factor models have their origin in macroeconomics, more specifically in empirical research on business cycles. The central idea, going back to the work of Burns and Mitchell in the 1940s, is that the fluctuations of all the macro and sectoral variables in the economy are driven by a “reference cycle,” that is, a one-dimensional latent cause of variation. After a fairly long process of generalization and formalization, the literature settled at the beginning of the 2000s on a model in which (a) both n, the number of variables in the data set, and T, the number of observations for each variable, may be large; (b) all the variables in the data set depend dynamically on a fixed, independent of n, number of common shocks, plus variable-specific, usually called idiosyncratic, components. The structure of the model can be exemplified as follows: (*)xit=αiut+βiut−1+ξit,i=1,…,n,t=1,…,T, where the observable variables xit are driven by the white noise ut, which is common to all the variables, the common shock, and by the idiosyncratic component ξit. The common shock ut is orthogonal to the idiosyncratic components ξit, the idiosyncratic components are mutually orthogonal (or weakly correlated). Last, the variations of the common shock ut affect the variable xitdynamically, that is, through the lag polynomial αi+βiL. Asymptotic results for high-dimensional factor models, consistency of estimators of the common shocks in particular, are obtained for both n and T tending to infinity. The time-domain approach to these factor models is based on the transformation of dynamic equations into static representations. For example, equation (∗) becomes xit=αiF1t+βiF2t+ξit,F1t=ut,F2t=ut−1. Instead of the dynamic equation (∗) there is now a static equation, while instead of the white noise ut there are now two factors, also called static factors, which are dynamically linked: F1t=ut,F2t=F1,t−1. This transformation into a static representation, whose general form is xit=λi1F1t+⋯+λirFrt+ξit, is extremely convenient for estimation and forecasting of high-dimensional dynamic factor models. In particular, the factors Fjt and the loadings λij can be consistently estimated from the principal components of the observable variables xit. Assumption allowing consistent estimation of the factors and loadings are discussed in detail. Moreover, it is argued that in general the vector of the factors is singular; that is, it is driven by a number of shocks smaller than its dimension. This fact has very important consequences. In particular, singularity implies that the fundamentalness problem, which is hard to solve in structural vector autoregressive (VAR) analysis of macroeconomic aggregates, disappears when the latter are studied as part of a high-dimensional dynamic factor model.


Statistics ◽  
2020 ◽  
Vol 54 (2) ◽  
pp. 415-423
Author(s):  
Serguey Khovansky ◽  
Oleksandr Zhylyevskyy

2005 ◽  
Vol 22 (1) ◽  
pp. 127-146 ◽  
Author(s):  
Pierre-Yves Hénin ◽  
Thomas Weitzenblum

2015 ◽  
Vol 64 ◽  
pp. 1-13 ◽  
Author(s):  
Kam Chuen Yuen ◽  
Zhibin Liang ◽  
Ming Zhou

2012 ◽  
Vol 12 (1) ◽  
pp. 1850252 ◽  
Author(s):  
Roman Horvath ◽  
Petr Poldauf

We investigate the stock market comovements in Australia, Brazil, Canada, China, Germany, Hong Kong, Japan, Russia, South Africa, the UK, and the USA, both at the market and sectoral level in 2000-2010. Using multivariate GARCH models, our results suggest that the correlation among equity returns during the financial crisis (2008-2010) somewhat increased, suggesting that the crisis represented a common shock to all countries. The U.S. stock market is found to be the most correlated with the stock markets in Brazil, Canada and UK. The correlation of U.S. and Chinese stock market is essentially zero before the crisis; it becomes slightly positive during the crisis. The sectoral indices are less correlated than the market indices over the whole period, but, again, the correlations increase during the crisis.


1987 ◽  
Vol 54 (3) ◽  
pp. 532-538 ◽  
Author(s):  
M. B. Rubin

Specific constitutive equations are proposed for a material exhibiting isotropic-elastic response in its reference configuration, strain-rate, temperature and density dependent plastic flow with isotropic and directional hardening, and thermal recovery of hardening. The shear modulus is temperature and density dependent and it vanishes when the temperature reaches the density dependent melting temperature. These equations include modifications, relative to those proposed by Rubin (1986), which are appropriate to describe metals subjected to high compression. The constitutive functions characterizing pressure are determined by comparison with a Mie-Gru¨neisen equation of state which includes functions that are obtained from common shock-wave experiments. To examine some of the features of these equations at high compression we consider an example of homogeneous uniaxial strain and show that the deviatoric stress may be quite large at ultra high compression rates and high compression.


2014 ◽  
Vol 27 (7) ◽  
pp. 1097-1114
Author(s):  
Doyoung Kim ◽  
Issac Lee ◽  
Hangsuck Lee
Keyword(s):  

Sign in / Sign up

Export Citation Format

Share Document