Effects of growth rates and cooling rates on defect generation in melt-grown copper crystals

1974 ◽  
Vol 24-25 ◽  
pp. 418-421 ◽  
Author(s):  
Tetsuo Inoue ◽  
Jirô Watanabé ◽  
Mikio Yamamoto
2018 ◽  
Vol 924 ◽  
pp. 116-119 ◽  
Author(s):  
Shi Yang Ji ◽  
Ryoji Kosugi ◽  
Kazutoshi Kojima ◽  
Kazuhiro Mochizuki ◽  
Yasuyuki Kawada ◽  
...  

By mapping the source and HCl flow rates dependent growth rates, the evolving trend of a quasi-selective epitaxial growth (quasi-SEG) that growing very thin epilayer on mesa top and ensuring an extremely low risk of voids defect generation was firstly figured out on a 5-μm 4H-SiC trench. Then, basing on the acquired knowledge, a 25-μm 4H-SiC trench with an aspect ratio up to ~10 was completely filled in the quasi-SEG mode.


1981 ◽  
Vol 34 (9) ◽  
pp. 1845 ◽  
Author(s):  
LH Cohen ◽  
Jr W Klement

Differential thermal analyses have located the transitions between low-temperature I and high-temperature II phases in AgNO3 powder and single crystals under hydrostatic pressures </~0.7 GPa, with heating/cooling rates in the range 0.1-1.5 K s-1. Isobaric transition temperatures plot linearly against heating/cooling rates and, extrapolated to zero rate, show hystereses between I → II and II → I transition temperatures which are comparable with the 'regions of indifference' of Bridgman's isothermal experiments. The present results suggest an initial slope of -0.090 μK Pa-1 and zero initial curvature for the I-II phase boundary. Greater hystereses are observed for the I-II transitions near intersection with the II-II' λ transition at </~0.7 GPa. An improved, quantitative description is achieved for the Kennedy-Schultz data on the linear growth rates of II,II? → I at 0.1 MPa. For II' (with ordered NO3- ions) → I the growth rates show temperature dependence markedly different than growth rates for II(with disordered NO3-) → 1 and I → II.


2018 ◽  
Vol 64 (248) ◽  
pp. 866-876 ◽  
Author(s):  
JOLANA HRUBA ◽  
GUNTHER KLETETSCHKA

ABSTRACTAutonomous temperature data loggers were used to measure the temperature profile within a growing ice cover and in the water below. The ice formed under natural conditions over the pond. We observed the presence of distinct layers of gas bubbles throughout the ice thickness. Temperature measurements allowed us to determine growth rates (μm s−1) and cooling rates (°C s−1) of the ice and demonstrated that these bubble layers formed during the peak ice growth rates from 0.58 to 0.92 µm s−1. The growth rates, leading to the formation of layers of bubbles, were more than an order of magnitude lower than for bubbles produced in controlled laboratory conditions (from 3 to 80 µm s−1). This observation introduces the possibility that solid impurities play a role in natural waters and that they must lower the limit of growth rates required for bubble occurrence. Data revealed a decrease in ice growth rates while cooling rates increased. We interpret this observation as an effect of the heat flux from the water to the ice (8.34–34.11 W m−2), and of gas concentration changes in the water below. Calculations of the ice thickness using traditional methods showed the necessity to include the heat flux from the water to the ice and the effect of gas bubbles within the ice and near the ice–water interface.


1966 ◽  
Vol 94 (4) ◽  
pp. 491-498 ◽  
Author(s):  
F. D. Malkinson
Keyword(s):  

2005 ◽  
pp. 4-18 ◽  
Author(s):  
K. Sonin

In unequal societies, the rich may benefit from shaping economic institutions in their favor. This paper analyzes the dynamics of institutional subversion by focusing on public protection of property rights. If this institution functions imperfectly, agents have incentives to invest in private protection of property rights. The ability to maintain private protection systems makes the rich natural opponents of public protection of property rights and precludes grass-roots demand to drive the development of the market-friendly institution. The economy becomes stuck in a bad equilibrium with low growth rates, high inequality of income, and wide-spread rent-seeking. The Russian oligarchs of the 1990s, who controlled large stakes of newly privatized property, provide motivation for this paper.


2014 ◽  
pp. 4-32 ◽  
Author(s):  
V. Mau

The paper deals with Russian social and economic development in 2013 and prospects for the next year or two. The author discusses the logic and trends of the global crisis started in 2008. This is the basis for further analysis of current Russian economic performance with special emphasis on the problem of growth rates deceleration. Special attention is paid to economic risks and priorities of economic policy.


2018 ◽  
pp. 76-94 ◽  
Author(s):  
I. A. Makarov ◽  
C. Henry ◽  
V. P. Sergey

The paper applies multiregional CGE Economic Policy Projection and Analysis (EPPA) model to analyze major risks the Paris Agreement on climate change adopted in 2015 brings to Russia. The authors come to the conclusion that if parties of the Agreement meet their targets that were set for 2030 it may lead to the decrease of average annual GDP growth rates by 0.2-0.3 p. p. Stricter climate policies beyond this year would bring GDP growth rates reduction in2035-2050 by additional 0.5 p. p. If Russia doesn’t ratify Paris Agreement, these losses may increase. In order to mitigate these risks, diversification of Russian economy is required.


Sign in / Sign up

Export Citation Format

Share Document