Too Good to Hire? Capability and Inferences about Commitment in Labor Markets

2019 ◽  
Vol 65 (2) ◽  
pp. 275-313 ◽  
Author(s):  
Roman V. Galperin ◽  
Oliver Hahl ◽  
Adina D. Sterling ◽  
Jerry Guo

We examine how signals of a candidate’s capability affect perceptions of that person’s commitment to an employer. In four experimental studies that use hiring managers as subjects, we test and show that managers perceive highly capable candidates to have lower commitment to the organization than less capable but adequate candidates and, as a result, penalize high-capability candidates in the hiring process. Our results show that managers have concerns about a high-capability candidate’s future commitment to the organization because they view highly capable candidates as having lower levels of organizational interest—meaning they care less about the mission and values of the organization and exert a lower level of effort toward those ends—and because they assume highly capable candidates have more outside job options, increasing their flight risk. Our findings highlight that capability signals do not necessarily afford candidates an advantage in selection, suggesting an upper limit on credentials and other signals of capability in helping candidates get jobs. Our study contributes to research on labor markets, human capital, and credentialing by offering a theory for why and when capability signals can negatively influence job candidate selection decisions.

2020 ◽  
pp. 174-194
Author(s):  
Phillip Brown

This chapter turns to questions of labor demand at the heart of the new human capital. It rejects Gary Becker’s claim that orthodox theory offered an entirely new way of looking at labor markets, where the main focus is on labor scarcity and a skills competition, in which individuals, firms, and nations compete on differential investments in education and training. It also rejects David Autor’s claim that the issue is not that middle-class workers are doomed by automation and technology, but instead that human capital investment must be at the heart of any long-term strategy for producing skills that are complemented by rather than substituted for by technological change. The chapter argues that the new human capital rejects the view that demand issues can be resolved through a combination of technological and educational solutions. Rather a jobs lens is required to shed new light on changes in the occupational structure, transforming the way people capitalize on their education, along with the distribution of individual life chances.


2004 ◽  
Vol 34 (3) ◽  
pp. 431-440 ◽  
Author(s):  
Jaime Orrillo ◽  
Paulo R. A. Loureiro

Assume a labor supply consisting of two types of workers, 1 and 2. Both workers are equally productive and exhibit supply functions with the same elasticity. We consider a firm (entrepreneur or shareholders) that is competitive in the output market and monopsonistic in input markets. The firm uses the services of a manager who has a high human capital and whose wage is given by the market. It is supposed that the manager does not like to work with one type of worker, say type 1. If we allow the manager's effort to be an additional input without any extra (in addition to his salary) cost for the firm, then the firm's pricing decision will be different for both workers. That is, there will be a wage differential and therefore endogenous economic discrimination2 in the labor markets.


2016 ◽  
Vol 44 (2) ◽  
pp. 210-232 ◽  
Author(s):  
Matthew A. Painter ◽  
Matthew R. Sanderson

This study builds on recent work investigating the process of migration channeling between analogous sectors of the Mexican and U.S. labor markets. In this study, the authors take up the question of whether channeling between Mexico and the United States promotes immigrants’ economic integration. Drawing on previous research on channeling, and using insights from human capital theory, the authors test the hypothesis that immigrants who are able to use their industry-specific knowledge, skills, and abilities acquired in Mexico within the same industry in the United States achieve higher levels of economic integration. Using a sample of Mexican immigrants from the New Immigrant Survey, we find that industrially channeled immigrants experience a wage premium of over $5,000, on average, in the United States. Our study concludes with a discussion of what industrial channeling means for Mexican immigrants’ broader integration into U.S. society.


1992 ◽  
Vol 38 (9) ◽  
pp. 1809-1818 ◽  
Author(s):  
W R Harris

Abstract An equilibrium model for the speciation of Al3+ in normal serum has been developed in which 81% of the aluminum is bound to transferrin. The remaining 19% exists primarily as Al(PO4)(OH)-, with minor amounts of citrate and hydroxide species. The model meets several key criteria. The concentration of free aluminum is below the upper limit set by the solubility product of aluminum phosphate. The fraction of low-molecular-mass aluminum species agrees with experimental studies on the fraction of ultrafiltrable aluminum in both normal and uremic serum. Lastly, the model accounts for the relative effectiveness of EDTA, citrate, and desferrioxamine B for binding aluminum in serum by including competition from zinc, magnesium, and calcium for these ligands. Uncertainties in the available thermodynamic database are discussed.


Sign in / Sign up

Export Citation Format

Share Document