technical assumption
Recently Published Documents


TOTAL DOCUMENTS

19
(FIVE YEARS 8)

H-INDEX

4
(FIVE YEARS 1)

Author(s):  
Salvatore Floccari

AbstractWe show that the André motive of a hyper-Kähler variety X over a field $$K \subset {\mathbb {C}}$$ K ⊂ C with $$b_2(X)>6$$ b 2 ( X ) > 6 is governed by its component in degree 2. More precisely, we prove that if $$X_1$$ X 1 and $$X_2$$ X 2 are deformation equivalent hyper-Kähler varieties with $$b_2(X_i)>6$$ b 2 ( X i ) > 6 and if there exists a Hodge isometry $$f:H^2(X_1,{\mathbb {Q}})\rightarrow H^2(X_2,{\mathbb {Q}})$$ f : H 2 ( X 1 , Q ) → H 2 ( X 2 , Q ) , then the André motives of $$X_1$$ X 1 and $$X_2$$ X 2 are isomorphic after a finite extension of K, up to an additional technical assumption in presence of non-trivial odd cohomology. As a consequence, the Galois representations on the étale cohomology of $$X_1$$ X 1 and $$X_2$$ X 2 are isomorphic as well. We prove a similar result for varieties over a finite field which can be lifted to hyper-Kähler varieties for which the Mumford–Tate conjecture is true.


Author(s):  
M.I. Gomoyunov ◽  
D.A. Serkov

In this paper, we deal with a control problem under conditions of disturbances, which is stated as a problem of optimization of the guaranteed result. Compared to the classical formulation of such problems, we assume that the set of admissible disturbances is finite and consists of piecewise continuous functions. In connection with this additional functional constraint on the disturbance, we introduce an appropriate class of non-anticipative control strategies and consider the corresponding value of the optimal guaranteed result. Under a technical assumption concerning a property of distinguishability of the admissible disturbances, we prove that this result can be achieved by using control strategies with full memory. As a consequence, we establish unimprovability of the class of full-memory strategies. A key element of the proof is a procedure of recovering the disturbance acting in the system, which allows us to associate every non-anticipative strategy with a full-memory strategy providing a close guaranteed result. The paper concludes with an illustrative example.


Author(s):  
Saskia Roos ◽  
Nobuhiko Otoba

AbstractFor a closed, connected direct product Riemannian manifold $$(M, g)=(M_1, g_1) \times \cdots \times (M_l, g_l)$$ ( M , g ) = ( M 1 , g 1 ) × ⋯ × ( M l , g l ) , we define its multiconformal class $$ [\![ g ]\!]$$ [ [ g ] ] as the totality $$\{f_1^2g_1\oplus \cdots \oplus f_l^2g_l\}$$ { f 1 2 g 1 ⊕ ⋯ ⊕ f l 2 g l } of all Riemannian metrics obtained from multiplying the metric $$g_i$$ g i of each factor $$M_i$$ M i by a positive function $$f_i$$ f i on the total space M. A multiconformal class $$ [\![ g ]\!]$$ [ [ g ] ] contains not only all warped product type deformations of g but also the whole conformal class $$[\tilde{g}]$$ [ g ~ ] of every $$\tilde{g}\in [\![ g ]\!]$$ g ~ ∈ [ [ g ] ] . In this article, we prove that $$ [\![ g ]\!]$$ [ [ g ] ] contains a metric of positive scalar curvature if and only if the conformal class of some factor $$(M_i, g_i)$$ ( M i , g i ) does, under the technical assumption $$\dim M_i\ge 2$$ dim M i ≥ 2 . We also show that, even in the case where every factor $$(M_i, g_i)$$ ( M i , g i ) has positive scalar curvature, $$ [\![ g ]\!]$$ [ [ g ] ] contains a metric of scalar curvature constantly equal to $$-1$$ - 1 and with arbitrarily large volume, provided $$l\ge 2$$ l ≥ 2 and $$\dim M\ge 3$$ dim M ≥ 3 .


2021 ◽  
Vol 157 (7) ◽  
pp. 1507-1537
Author(s):  
Huanchen Bao ◽  
Weiqiang Wang

For quantum symmetric pairs $(\textbf {U}, \textbf {U}^\imath )$ of Kac–Moody type, we construct $\imath$ -canonical bases for the highest weight integrable $\textbf U$ -modules and their tensor products regarded as $\textbf {U}^\imath$ -modules, as well as an $\imath$ -canonical basis for the modified form of the $\imath$ -quantum group $\textbf {U}^\imath$ . A key new ingredient is a family of explicit elements called $\imath$ -divided powers, which are shown to generate the integral form of $\dot {\textbf {U}}^\imath$ . We prove a conjecture of Balagovic–Kolb, removing a major technical assumption in the theory of quantum symmetric pairs. Even for quantum symmetric pairs of finite type, our new approach simplifies and strengthens the integrality of quasi- $K$ -matrix and the constructions of $\imath$ -canonical bases, by avoiding a case-by-case rank-one analysis and removing the strong constraints on the parameters in a previous work.


2021 ◽  
Vol 2021 (1) ◽  
Author(s):  
Hong Qiu ◽  
Wenmin Deng ◽  
Mingqi Xiang

AbstractThe aim of this paper is to investigate the optimal harvesting strategies of a stochastic competitive Lotka–Volterra model with S-type distributed time delays and Lévy jumps by using ergodic method. Firstly, the sufficient conditions for extinction and stable in the time average of each species are established under some suitable assumptions. Secondly, under a technical assumption, the stability in distribution of this model is proved. Then the sufficient and necessary criteria for the existence of optimal harvesting policy are established under the condition that all species are persistent. Moreover, the explicit expression of the optimal harvesting effort and the maximum of sustainable yield are given.


Author(s):  
Mingyu Guo

We study the classic public project problem, where a group of agents need to decide whether or not to build a non-excludable public project.  We focus on efficient, strategy-proof, and weakly budget-balanced mechanisms (VCG redistribution mechanisms). Our aim is to maximize the worst-case efficiency ratio --- the worst-case ratio between the achieved total utility and the first-best maximum total utility. Previous studies have identified the optimal mechanism for 3 agents.  It was also conjectured that the worst-case efficiency ratio approaches 1 asymptotically as the number of agents approaches infinity.  Unfortunately, no optimal mechanisms have been identified for cases with more than 3 agents. We propose an asymptotically optimal mechanism, which achieves a worst-case efficiency ratio of 1, under a minor technical assumption: we assume the agents' valuations are rational numbers with bounded denominators.  We also show that if the agents' valuations are drawn from identical and independent distributions, our mechanism's efficiency ratio equals 1 with probability approaching 1 asymptotically.  Our results significantly improve on previous results. The best previously known asymptotic worst-case efficiency ratio is 0.102.  For non-asymptotic cases, our mechanisms also achieve better ratios than all previous results.  


2019 ◽  
Vol 6 (4) ◽  
pp. 190381 ◽  
Author(s):  
Daniel Strömbom ◽  
Tasnia Hassan ◽  
W. Hunter Greis ◽  
Alice Antia

Animal groups frequently move in a highly organized manner, as represented by flocks of birds and schools of fish. Despite being an everyday occurrence, we do not fully understand how this works. In particular, what social interactions between animals give rise to the flock structures we observe? This question is often investigated using self-propelled particle models where particles represent the individual animals. These models differ in the social interactions used, individual particle properties, and various technical assumptions. One particular technical assumption relates to whether all particles update their headings and positions at exactly the same time (synchronous update) or not (asynchronous update). Here, we investigate the causal effects of this assumption in an attraction-only model and find that it has a dramatic impact. Polarized groups do not form when synchronous update is used, but are produced with asynchronous update, and this phenomenon is robust with respect to variation in particle displacements and inclusion of noise. Given that many important models have been implemented with synchronous update only, we speculate that our understanding of the social interactions on which they are based may be incomplete. Perhaps previously unobserved phenomena will emerge if other potentially more realistic update schemes are used.


2019 ◽  
Vol 19 (1) ◽  
pp. 131-143 ◽  
Author(s):  
Abimbola Abolarinwa

Abstract Let ∆φ = ∆ − ∇φ∇ be a symmetric diffusion operator with an invariant weighted volume measure dμ = e−φ dν on an n-dimensional compact Riemannian manifold (M, g), where g = g(t) solves the extended Ricci flow. We study the evolution and monotonicity of the first nonzero eigenvalue of ∆φ and we obtain several monotone quantities along the extended Ricci flow and its volume preserving version under some technical assumption. We also show that the eigenvalues diverge in a finite time for n ≥ 3. Our results are natural extensions of some known results for Laplace–Beltrami operators under various geometric flows.


Author(s):  
Ercüment H. Ortaçgil

Even though it is quite clear at this stage what curvature means, its technical definition turns out to be problematic, since it needs a technical assumption. However, this assumption forces a projective structure to be flat, and it becomes necessary to modify the approach adopted so far.


Author(s):  
Gustavo Esteva

Development was born as aid, an expression of the modern obsession with “caring” used by disabling professions and the service industry. However, by 1980, it was already clear that there was no correlation between aid and economic growth, and that aid was an obstacle for social transformation. Development was also born in the context of the Cold War. For President Truman, the American way of life was a democratic and egalitarian ideal to overcome the communist “threat” by closing the gap between industrial and “underdeveloped” countries. In addition, development was a reaction to the initiatives of the colonized world, increasingly challenging Western domination. Since Truman, development has connoted at least one thing: to escape from the vague, indefinable, and undignified condition known as underdevelopment. However, the Age of Development—the historical period formally inaugurated in 1949—is now coming to an end. The future of development studies lies in archaeology, to explore the ruins it left behind by looking at development’s pre-history and conceptual history, as well as the development enterprise. Since the 1970s, new campaigns were launched to focus the effort in getting for the underdeveloped, at least, the fulfillment of their “basic needs.” Meanwhile, the “law of scarcity” was construed by the economists to denote the technical assumption that man’s wants are huge and infinite, whereas his means are limited though improvable. Poverty and development thus go hand in hand. Indeed, historical experience reveals that development generates poverty. By 1985, the idea of post-development has already emerged.


Sign in / Sign up

Export Citation Format

Share Document