The theory of value and distribution and the problem of capital

2020 ◽  
Vol 17 (2) ◽  
pp. 241-264
Author(s):  
Heinz D. Kurz

The paper identifies as the root of the recent controversy in the theory of capital David Ricardo's finding that competitive prices and costs of production depend not only on the methods of production employed, but also on the wage rate (or rate of profits) and change with it. A consequence of this result, whose systematic elaboration we owe to Piero Sraffa, is that systems of production cannot generally be ordered monotonically with the rate of profits. Reswitching, capital reversing, price and quantity Wicksell effects, etc., are all rooted in this fact. It is argued that the rate of profits is not determined by the marginal productivity of capital and that the equality between the two in equilibrium must not be misinterpreted as implying a causal relationship leading from the latter to the former. Attempts to assess the empirical probability of reswitching, etc., in terms of input–output tables ought to be received with many reservations for both theoretical and data-related reasons. It is further argued that problems for marginalist theory already arise in a zero-profit framework, in which compound interest effects are ruled out. Hence the seemingly unobtrusive ‘laws’ of input demand and output supply are a much less reliable basis to stand on than is conventionally thought. The paper concludes with some remarks on the implications of the findings in the controversy for Keynes's theory of investment.

Author(s):  
John Kibara Manyeki ◽  
Izabella Szakálné Kanó ◽  
Balázs Kotosz

Despite there being incredible challenges in enhancing livestock development in Kenya, this article isolates product supply and factors input demand responsiveness as the main constraints facing the smallholder. A flexible-Translog profit function permits the application of dual theory in the analysis of livestock product supply and factor demand responsiveness using farm-level household data. The results indicate that own-price elasticities were elastic for cattle, while goat and sheep were inelastic. Cross-price and scale elasticities were found to be within inelastic range in all cases, with the goat being a preferred substitute for cattle. All factor inputs demand elasticities were inelastic with the exception of elastic cattle output prices and labour cost. Thus, the recommended policy option would be supportive pro-pastoral price policies, enhanced investment in pastureland improvement and an increasing wage rate, since these assume key significance in improving the livestock production/marketing.


1994 ◽  
Vol 24 (94) ◽  
pp. 143-165
Author(s):  
Klaus Schabacker

Sraffa's Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities shows a system of price equations which requires an exogenous determination either of the wage rate or the rate of profit. The fault of classical, Marxian and early neoclassical theory lies within their attempt to derive a rate of profit from a given magnitude called capital. The rate of profit is conceived of as a concept of production. Both, the modern Neoclassics and Sraffa, reject such a view. The former resolves the problem of determining the rate of profit into an intertemporal equilibrium of prices and regards the Sraffanian theory of value as a special case of a general equilibrium. This paper argues that, on the contrary, Sraffa has proposed an alternative approach to the theory of price determination, because he suggests that the rate of profit should be derived from the rate of interest on money. The latter may forma part of a monetary theory, which can cope with the problem of unemployment while neoclassiscal theory submits the problem of employment to a theory of allocation.


2019 ◽  
Author(s):  
Uyiosa Omoregie

A widely-held proposition is that an enterprise does not create value until it commences production of goods or services for external customers for monetary profit. Another related proposition is that employees in a ‘non-producing’ enterprise, if remunerated, are paid 100 percent above the value of their labour – because the enterprise is not creating value. Counter arguments to these two propositions are presented. The purpose of a firm or business enterprise is discussed and the nature of ‘value’ is elaborated with a critique of the dominant marginal productivity theory of value.


2001 ◽  
Vol 23 (3) ◽  
pp. 301-317 ◽  
Author(s):  
Paul A. Samuelson

The Nobel Prize of Piero Sraffa and Joan Robinson that Stockholm never awarded might have pleased at least one of them. Its citation would have included: “Their investigations uncovered a fatal normative flaw in Böhm-Bawerkian and modern mainstream capital theory.”Just prior to Alfred Marshall's 1890 ascendancy as leading world economist, Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk (1851–1914) perhaps wore that crown thanks to his three-volume treatise on the history and fundamentals of interest theories. Böhm (1884, 1889, 1909, 1912) somewhat independently followed in the footsteps of Stanley Jevons (1871) and himself strongly stimulated Knut Wicksell (1893), Irving Fisher (1906, 1907, 1930), and Friedrich Hayek (1931, 1941). Pugnacious and somewhat incoherent, Böhm and his disciples battled cogently the competing school of John Bates Clark (1899) and Frank Knight (1934, 1935a, 1935b), which idealized a permanent scalar capital alleged to be virtually permanent and with a marginal productivity determining its interest rate in much the same way that primary labor's marginal productivity determines its real wage rate and primary land's marginal productivity determines its real rent rate(s). The Clark-Knight paradigm—and, for that matter, Frank Ramsey's 1928 mathematical clone—shares the Böhm-Hayek vital normative flaw.


Author(s):  
Bishnu Prasad Sharma

 Labour market imperfections are one of the leading causes of economic backwardness that result in under utilization of labour, the most important input in production process. Labour markets are shallow in subsistence agricultural economies which causes problem in determining the wage rate. The household production function provides an alternative to estimating the shadow wage rate such that it reflects the opportunity cost of labour. The most important deductions of the household production function are: the marginal productivity of labour is its shadow wage rate and; at equilibrium, the marginal returns from labour are exactly equal across all activities. This paper uses data collected in 2008 in course of a leasehold forestry study from 297 households from Makwanpur district of Nepal using a multi stage sampling. This paper estimates the marginal productivity of labour in maize production, the most common form of economic activity, for male and female labour. It examines how the money wage rate and the actual wage rate may differ from the shadow wage rate reflected by marginal productivity of labour in agriculture. The findings reveal that the actual wage rate for male labour is inflated and exceeds its marginal productivity while female wage rate slightly understates its marginal productivity. The paper concludes with policy recommendation of ensuring institutional mechanisms to correct for these imperfections. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.3126/ejdi.v15i1-2.11860 Economic Journal of Development Issues Vol. 15 & 16 No. 1-2, pp. 24-35 


2011 ◽  
Vol 20 (3) ◽  
Author(s):  
Amaechi N. Nwaokoro

<p class="MsoBlockText" style="margin: 0in 31.5pt 0pt;"><span style="font-style: normal; font-size: 10pt; mso-bidi-font-style: italic;"><span style="font-family: Times New Roman;">The period of 1963-1988 witnessed a tremendous decline in U.S. steel employment while the real wage rate increased slightly in the industry.<span style="mso-spacerun: yes;">&nbsp; </span>There is a popular notion that the nominal wage rate is the major factor in explaining the declining steel employment.<span style="mso-spacerun: yes;">&nbsp; </span>This study examines the decline in a system of input demand equations based on time series data.<span style="mso-spacerun: yes;">&nbsp; </span>The study identifies a heavy cap-italization in the industry as the driving factor for the steel employment decline.<span style="mso-spacerun: yes;">&nbsp; </span>This result supports the claim that the high wage rate in the industry is backed up by high productivity and therefore is not responsible for the steel employment decline.<span style="mso-spacerun: yes;">&nbsp; </span>Also, the study finds a lot of input substitutions.<span style="mso-spacerun: yes;">&nbsp; </span>The study finds diseconomies of scale in the industry, which may explain the decline of the industry.</span></span></p>


Author(s):  
A. E. Ritchie

The cause of bluecomb disease in turkeys is unknown. Filtration of infective intestinal contents suggests a viral origin. To date, it has not been possible to isolate the etiologic agent in various cell cultures. The purpose of this work was to characterize as many virus-like entities as were recognizable in intestines of both healthy and bluecomb-infected turkeys. By a comparison of the viral populations it was hoped that some insight might be gained into the cause of this disease. Studies of turkey hemorraghic enteritis by Gross and Moore (Avian Dis. 11: 296-307, 1967) have suggested that a bacteriophage-host cell interaction may bear some causal relationship to that disease.


2008 ◽  
Vol 39 (3) ◽  
pp. 141-150 ◽  
Author(s):  
Rainer Reisenzein ◽  
Irina Mchitarjan

According to Heider, some of his ideas about common-sense psychology presented in The Psychology of Interpersonal Relations ( Heider, 1958 ) originally came from his academic teacher, Alexius Meinong. However, Heider makes no reference to Meinong in his book. To clarify Meinong’s influence on Heider, we compare Heider’s explication of common-sense psychology with Meinong’s writings, in particular those on ethics. Our results confirm that Heider’s common-sense psychology is informed by Meinong’s psychological analyses in several respects: Heider adopts aspects of Meinong’s theory of emotion, his theory of value, and his theory of responsibility attribution. In addition, Heider more or less continues Meinong’s method of psychological inquiry. Thus, even without Meinong’s name attached, many aspects of Meinong’s psychology found their way into today’s social psychology via Heider. Unknowingly, some of us have been Meinongians all along.


Sign in / Sign up

Export Citation Format

Share Document