scholarly journals As indústrias têxtil e do vestuário na Comunidade Económica Europeia. Os novos factores de competitividade

Finisterra ◽  
2012 ◽  
Vol 30 (59/60) ◽  
Author(s):  
Iva Pires

THE EEC TEXTILE AND CLOTHING INDUSTRIES, THE NEW COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGES - In spite of using new technologies, the textile and clothing industries remain intensive in workforce and thus sensitive to wage costs. The European firms must therefore find other competitive advantages based on product differentiation, quality and design. German and Italian T&C industries are good examples of how quality and design can help "mature" industries maintain a successful place in the world market. Nevertheless, the cost of production remains a problem. The use of the outwear processing traffic (OPT) allows the European textile industry to mantain the quality patterns of its products, profiting from cheap workforce. This more advantageous situation is due both to innovation and to low production costs.

2020 ◽  
Vol 142 (10) ◽  
pp. 38-43
Author(s):  
Amiyo K. Basu

Abstract There were two breakthroughs that led to a veritable revolution in photovoltaic prices. The commonly told story is that China started manufacturing lower-quality panels and dumped them on the world market at prices near (or even below) the cost of production. The truth is more complicated. Chinese manufacturing at scale played a part, but so did German industrial policy and a focus on improving the complete power system, not just the PV cells.


Author(s):  
Svetlana Nesterenko

The article considers the issue of studying the competitiveness of Ukrainian mineral products and establishing prospects for its increase in the world market in terms of regional processes. Factors influencing the competitiveness of the industry and products were identified internal and external. External ones include: activities of state authorities, economic conditions, development of new technologies, new materials and energy sources, market capacity and demand structure, consumer requirements, etc. The competitive advantages of the industry are resource and technology. To internal - the reputation of the enterprise, its organizational and production activities, staff qualifications, efficiency of resource potential, system of technological equipment, volumes and costs of sales. Among the factors of product competitiveness are the following: usefulness for the consumer (compliance with the requirements for this product by the buyer), product price, novelty (originality and uniqueness of the product), product quality. Based on the analysis of the competitiveness of Ukrainian mineral products on the world market, it was determined that Ukraine has a very large potential in the development of this sector on the world stage, as it is well supplied with many mineral resources. However, they are not always extracted rationally. During 2014-2020, the share of mineral products in total exports of Ukrainian goods decreased, which was due to reduced production during this period, state protectionism in traditional for Ukrainian products importing countries, lower prices for goods, including energy, closing Russian market for Ukrainian products. At the same time, during the analyzed period, the volume of exports of Ukrainian mineral products increased. Demand for mineral products in the raw materials market is increasing, especially for scarce products, but imports significantly outweigh exports, due to lack of state support for the development of Ukraine's mineral resources, significant depreciation of technologies and lack of development of new deposits and efficient use of existing ones.


2020 ◽  
Vol 4 (1) ◽  
pp. 81-87
Author(s):  
Shinta Dwi Ardanari ◽  
Rynalto Mukiwihando

ABSTRACTShare of Indonesia's export value of natural rubber in the international market is almost always below Thailand, which is one of the competiting countries. The others countries began to become a threat to Indonesia because their exports share of natural rubber showed an increasing. This indicates that there is intense competition in the international market. As a country with the largest plantation area in the world, Indonesia should be superior. But this can be an opportunity to be able to compete in the world market so it is important to be managed more deeply so that it can create competitive advantages that can increase competitiveness. This study aims to determine the position of the competitiveness of natural rubber exports for the three countries of ITRC in the international market. The analytical method used is dynamic RCA. The results showed that all products of natural rubber coded HS 400110, 400121, 400122, 400129 and 400130 were experiencing a decline in growth in the export share of the three countries of ITRC : Indonesia, Thailand and Malaysia, but the market demand conditions for these products were declining in that time period.


Author(s):  
Viktoriya Bondarenko

The level of economic development of entrepreneurship in any country in the world is crucial in increasing the competitiveness of the national economy in the world market of goods and services. The activities of economic entities are the driving force for the sustainable development of regions and their suburban areas, and they also impact the welfare of population. The article dwells on the analysis of scientific approaches to the regulation of economic development of enterprises in suburban areas of the region. The article analyzes the scientific approaches to the regulation of economic development of enterprises in suburban areas of the region. According to the well-known classics of the fundamental economic theory of entrepreneurship development (A. Smith, D. Ricardo, V. Laungard, A. Loria) the peculiarities of economic development of entrepreneurship in suburban territories of the region are determined by the possibility of distribution of surplus production, minimum production costs per unit of production, availability of labor resources. In modern economic theory (M. Weber, A. Pre, S.M. Kimelberg, E. Williams, C. Vlachou, O. Iakovidou, J. van Dijk, P. Pellenbarg) the development of entrepreneurship in suburban areas of the region can be determined by institutional, innovation, technological, social, ecological and other features of the economy at the regional, state or world levels. The complex and comprehensive generalization of the features of economic development of entrepreneurship in suburban areas is proposed. There are (1) the type of decision taken by an enterprise to carry out business activities in the relevant suburban area of the region, and (2) the influence of internal and external factors on economic activity. The article argues that large enterprises are guided by more objective decision-making reasons, attaching the most importance to the physical and innovative environment. Medium and small enterprises are mainly focused on getting benefits for the entrepreneur in the short-term time period and location in the nearest geographic area. The attention was paid to the tools of ensuring economic development of entrepreneurship in suburban areas of the region, taking into account institutional changes in the national economy and the experience of developed countries of the world.


Agriculture ◽  
2021 ◽  
Vol 11 (6) ◽  
pp. 494
Author(s):  
Riccardo Lo Bianco ◽  
Primo Proietti ◽  
Luca Regni ◽  
Tiziano Caruso

The objective of fully mechanizing olive harvesting has been pursued since the 1970s to cope with labor shortages and increasing production costs. Only in the last twenty years, after adopting super-intensive planting systems and developing appropriate straddle machines, a solution seems to have been found. The spread of super-intensive plantings, however, raises serious environmental and social concerns, mainly because of the small number of cultivars that are currently used (basically 2), compared to over 100 cultivars today cultivated on a large scale across the world. Olive growing, indeed, insists on over 11 million hectares. Despite its being located mostly in the Mediterranean countries, the numerous olive growing districts are characterized by deep differences in climate and soil and in the frequency and nature of environmental stress. To date, the olive has coped with biotic and abiotic stress thanks to the great cultivar diversity. Pending that new technologies supporting plant breeding will provide a wider number of cultivars suitable for super-intensive systems, in the short term, new growing models must be developed. New olive orchards will need to exploit cultivars currently present in various olive-growing areas and favor increasing productions that are environmentally, socially, and economically sustainable. As in fruit growing, we should focus on “pedestrian olive orchards”, based on trees with small canopies and whose top can be easily reached by people from the ground and by machines (from the side of the top) that can carry out, in a targeted way, pesticide treatments, pruning and harvesting.


2020 ◽  
Vol 17 (2) ◽  
pp. 129-140
Author(s):  
D Damayanti ◽  
A I Jaya ◽  
Resnawati

ABSTRACT The purpose of this research is to obtain an the optimal production costs of Klappertart based on the basic ingredients comparing the production cost of Klappertart in Najmah Klappertart with production costs using the simplex method. The result showed that the optimal costs is ,-. This result is equal to the total cost of klappertart by SMEs Najmah Klappertart, so it can be concluded that the cost of production klappertart based on the basic ingredients on SMEs Najmah Klappertart were optimal. Keywords      : Optimal Cost, Basic Ingredients, Production Costs. (A-Z), Simplex Method  


Author(s):  
Daniel Fuentes ◽  
Rosalía Laza ◽  
Antonio Pereira

The rural wireless networks are increasingly in demand by associations and autarchies to expand Internet access in this type of areas. The problem of such solutions centers not only in network deployment and its maintenance, but also in the equipment installation on clients, which always has big costs. This installation and configuration must be performed by a technician on site, so that the equipment can be integrated in the infrastructure. To try to mitigate this problem, it is presented a solution that allows the clients to install, with transparency, the device at home, reducing not only the cost for the management entity but also for the clients. This way, for info-excluded people or with new technology low experience level, it is the user that integrates himself in the network, making him part of the process, fostering the network usage.In this article are specified not only the system architecture but also the way that it works and how it obtains the desirable result. The tests made to the solution show the quickness, reliability and autonomy in the execution of the tasks, making it a benefit for rural wireless networks.This solution, by its robustness and simplicity, allowed an uptake to the IT by people who never thought to do it, namely an advanced age group (elderly) who want to join the world of the new technologies


2019 ◽  
Vol 4 (1) ◽  
pp. 28-42
Author(s):  
Suprianto Suprianto ◽  
Bina Andari ◽  
Yely Sulistyawati

This study aims to evaluate the calculation of cost of production. The accuracy of the calculation of cost of production is influenced by the suitability in the accumulation and calculation of production costs which includes the cost of raw materials, direct labor costs and other costs (factory overhead costs). This research was conducted at UKM UD. Usaha Baru which aims to determine the calculation of cost of production at UD. Usaha Baru and to find out whether the calculation of cost of production is in accordance with the full costing method. The technique (method) of data analysis used in this study is quantitative analysis. Data collection techniques use interview techniques directly to obtain information from the number of units of monthly production, raw material costs, direct labor costs, and factory overhead costs, as well as other information relating to the calculation of cost of production. Based on the evaluation results for the calculation of raw material costs and labor costs are in accordance with the full costing method. However, the calculation of factory overhead costs is not in accordance with the full costing method because there are costs that have not been included in the calculation of production costs.


2017 ◽  
Vol 33 (4) ◽  
pp. 469-487 ◽  
Author(s):  
Ka Yi Fung

Adapting the framework of dependency theory, the article asks how the economic dependency of less developed countries (LDCs) on developed countries (DCs) is created through free trade. This article uses South Korea’s entry into the World Trade Organization (WTO) as a case study to illustrate this economic dependency creation process. Based on second-hand data from existing studies, the European Union, and the WTO, this article finds: (i) due to limited farmland size and high production costs, South Korean agricultural products cannot win a seat in the world market; (ii) the local agricultural sector was destroyed in South Korea because small farmers cannot earn a living by farming; and (iii) since the local agricultural sector cannot support the food demand in South Korea, South Korea now has to import a large amount of food. This article concludes that free trade actually destroys the local agricultural industry and the food security of South Korea, and consequently makes South Korea have to rely heavily on DCs for food import.


2016 ◽  
Author(s):  
Mark Lemley

Things are valuable because they are scarce. The more abundant they become,they cheaper they become. But a series of technological changes is underwaythat promises to end scarcity as we know it for a wide variety of goods.The Internet is the most obvious example, because the change there isfurthest along. The Internet has reduced the cost of production anddistribution of informational content effectively to zero. In many cases ithas also dramatically reduced the cost of producing that content. And ithas changed the way in which information is distributed, separating thecreators of content from the distributors.More recently, new technologies promise to do for a variety of physicalgoods and even services what the Internet has already done for information.3D printers can manufacture physical goods based on any digital design.Synthetic biology has automated the manufacture not just of copies ofexisting genetic sequences but any custom-made gene sequence, allowinganyone who want to create a gene sequence of their own to upload thesequence to a company that will “print” it using the basic building blocksof genetics. And advances in robotics offer the prospect that many of theservices humans now provide can be provided free of charge bygeneral-purpose machines that can be programmed to perform a variety ofcomplex functions. While none of these technologies are nearly as far alongas the Internet, they share two essential characteristics with theInternet: they radically reduce the cost of production and distribution ofthings, and they separate the informational content of those things (thedesign) from their manufacture. Combine these four developments – theInternet, 3D printing, robotics, and synthetic biology – and it is entirelyplausible to envision a not-too-distant world in which most things thatpeople want can be downloaded and created on site for very little money.The role of IP in such a world is both controverted and criticallyimportant. IP rights are designed to artificially replicate scarcity whereit would not otherwise exist. In its simplest form, IP law takes publicgoods that would otherwise be available to all and artificially restrictstheir distribution. It makes ideas scarce, because then we can bring theminto the economy and charge for them, and economics knows how to deal withscarce things. So on one view – the classical view of IP law – a world inwhich all the value resides in information is a world in which we need IPeverywhere, controlling rights over everything, or no one will get paid tocreate. That has been the response of IP law to the Internet so far.But that response is problematic for a couple of reasons. First, it doesn’tseem to be working. By disaggregating creation, production, anddistribution, the Internet democratized access to content. Copyright ownershave been unable to stop a flood of piracy with 50,000 lawsuits, a host ofnew and increasingly draconian laws, and a well-funded public educationcampaign that starts in elementary school. Second, even if we could use IPto rein in all this low-cost production and distribution of stuff, we maynot want to. The point of IP has always been, not to raise prices andreduce consumption for its own sake, but to encourage people to createthings when they otherwise wouldn’t. More and more evidence casts doubt onthe link between IP and creation, however. Empirical evidence suggests thatoffering money may actually stifle rather than drive creativity amongindividuals. Economic evidence suggests that quite often it is competition,not the lure of monopoly, that drives corporate innovation. The Internetmay have spawned unprecedented piracy, but it has also given rise to thecreation of more works of all types than ever before in history, often bymultiple orders of magnitude.Far from necessitating more IP protection, then, the development ofcost-reducing technologies may actually weaken the case for IP. If peopleare intrinsically motivated to create, as they seem to be, the easier it isto create and distribute content, the more content is likely to beavailable even in the absence of IP. And if the point of IP is to encourageeither the creation or the distribution of that content, cost-reducingtechnologies may actually mean we have less, not more, need for IP.IP rights are a form of government regulation of market entry and marketprices. We regulated all sorts of industries in the 20th century, fromairlines to trucking to telephones to electric power, often because wecouldn’t conceive of how the industry could survive without the governmentpreventing entry by competitors. Towards the end of that century, however,we experimented with deregulation, and it turned out that the market couldprovide many of those services better in the absence of governmentregulation. The same thing may turn out to be true of IP regulation in the21st century. We didn’t get rid of all regulation by any means, and wewon’t get rid of all IP. But we came to understand that the free market,not government control over entry, is the right default position in theabsence of a persuasive justification for limiting that market. Theelimination of scarcity will put substantial pressure on the law to do thesame with IP.A world without scarcity requires a major rethinking of economics, much asthe decline of the agrarian economy did in the 19th century. How will oureconomy function in a world in which most of the things we produce arecheap or free? We have lived with scarcity for so long that it is hard evento begin to think about the transition to a post-scarcity economy. IP hasallowed us to cling to scarcity as an organizing principle in a world thatno longer demands it. But it will no more prevent the transition thanagricultural price supports kept us all farmers. We need a post-scarcityeconomics, one that accepts rather than resists the new opportunitiestechnology will offer us. Developing that economics is the great task ofthe 21st century.


Sign in / Sign up

Export Citation Format

Share Document